The question whether or not government expansion causes economic growth has divided policy makers into two distinctive theoretical camps, as proponents of either big government or small government. Economic theory would suggest that on some occasions lower levels of government spending would enhance economic growth while on other occasions higher levels of government spending would be more desirable. From an empirical perspective the evidence generated becomes more confusing as a number of studies favor one or the other approach.

The substantial growth of the size of government expenditures in both the developed and developing nations since World War II, and its effect(s) on long-run economic growth (or vice versa), has spawned a vast literature that offers diverse attempts to explain the observed phenomenon. On the one hand, public finance studies have been directed towards identifying the principal causes of public sector growth. Wagner’s Law of public expenditure is one of the earliest attempts that emphasize economic growth as the fundamental determinant of public sector growth. The literature on this topic is immense to say the least. Some studies find a significant positive relationship between public sector growth and economic growth only developing nations but not for developed countries. Others even report a negative relationship between government spending and GNP.

On the other hand, macroeconomics, especially the Keynesian school of thought puts the emphasis on a different place. The analysis bears upon the question of the role of government in economic growth. A considerable amount of attention has been directed towards assessing the effect of the general flow of government services on economic growth. During the last twenty years or so, studying the underlying causal process Henrekson and Lybeck (1988) provide an excellent survey of various hypothesis between government spending and GDP, or their close variants, has made parallel efforts. The principle reason that led researchers to this field of analysis was the difficulty of a possible feedback in macro relations, which tend to obscure both the direction and the nature of causality.

According to some authors, there are two macroeconomic reasons why government spending can undermine economic performance. The first reason is “resource displacement.” Every time the government spends money, it is using labor and/or capital and those resources no longer are available for private sector uses.

The second macroeconomic issue associated with government spending is the “financing cost.” When government taxes, it not only takes money from the productive sector, but it also raises revenue by means of a tax system that generally reduces incentives to work, save, and invest. And if it finances spending with debt, it siphons money out of private credit markets.

The economic impact of government spending can be presented in graphical form by Rahn Curve ho is the equivalent for expenditure to Laffer Curve. In 1986, Richard Rahn, then the chief economist for the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, charted an inverse relationship between government spending and economic growth for the seven major industrialized countries in the form of a curve, not unlike the "Laffer Curve," which focused on the incentive effects of taxation.

The theory behind the "Rahn Curve" is that, at first, low levels of government spending on basic public services, such as law and order and a judicial system to enforce contracts, stimulate growth in the economy. But as spending rises as a share of the economy, its contribution to economic growth diminishes. Government spending eventually reaches a point where it actually retards economic growth.

There are several reasons for this. First, the growing public sector "crowds out" private sector activity, and it often uses the economy's resources far less efficiently. Second, as government grows bigger, it tends to accept broader responsibilities such as reducing poverty. This increased spending on welfare and income transfer programs, however, creates severe work disincentives. Third, an expanding government bureaucracy usually is accompanied by more complicated and burdensome regulation that stifles innovation and productivity. Fourth, the higher tax burdens necessary to finance bigger government at some point damage incentives to work, save and invest. The weakened economy fails to generate enough tax revenue to finance the ever-growing spending share, resulting in increased public sector borrowing and debt service burdens.

More Jorge Morales Pedraza's questions See All
Similar questions and discussions